October 2000
The
Untapped Potential of Water Privatization
By
Edwin S. Rubenstein
TABLE OF CONTENTS
Recommendations..................................................................................................... 4
Introduction............................................................................................................... 5
Competition in the Water Industry.............................................................................. 8
How Big is the U.S. Water Industry?....................................................................... 11
Factors Driving Water Privatization.......................................................................... 12
The Superiority of Privatization: A
Statistical Analysis…………………………
Can We Afford Water? Equity versus Efficiency....................................................... 15
Privatization Models................................................................................................ 17
Barriers to Private
Ownership.......................................................... 20
Other Regulatory Models :
Franchise Bidding (The
French Model)…………………………
Rate Caps (The British Model)…………………………………
The Future: Water Industry Scenarios……………………………………………..
Case Study: Atlanta: A Liberal mayor Embraces Privatization………………….28
A HUDSON INSTITUTE REPORT
FOR AMERICAN WATER WORKS, INC.
By Edwin S. Rubenstein
Executive Summary
Americans enjoy the best water service in the world. It’s so good we
think little about it. Turn on the tap and water comes running.
Yet getting that water to the
customer is a huge business. And the U.
S. lags far behind much of the rest of the world in how we treat water
utilities.
Privatization of water utilities is
becoming commonplace in much of the world.
In France, water utilities are private.
Some are quite large and have worldwide operations: Vivendi and Suez
Lyonnaise des Eaux are examples.
Britain’s government water monopoly was broken into eight large private
water utilities by Margaret Thatcher.
Much of the developing world gives concession contracts to private water
utilities to build and operate their expanding systems. Worldwide, just $300 million was spent on
water privatization between 1984 and 1990.
In the next seven years, more than $24 billion was spent. There is
no question where the rest of the world is moving.
The U. S.
lags this worldwide trend. Only about
15% of U. S. water customers are served by privately owned water
utilities. The vast bulk – some 24,000
water utilities – are owned by a municipality, a water authority, or a federal
entity. These publicly owned entities
sell water at subsidized rates. They increasingly contract out at least some of
their operations to private firms. It is
truly ironic that the capitalist and entrepreneurial United States has far more
government control of water than neo-socialist France.
Here are key findings regarding the
U.S. water industry:
-
WATER UTILITIES ARE THE MOST CAPITAL INTENSIVE OF PUBLIC
UTILITIES. They require up to three
times more capital to generate a dollar of revenue than electric
utilities. A water utility may require
up to $12 in capital plant investment for every $1 in revenue generated,
compared to something more like $4 for electric utilities (thought of as also
very capital intensive). This makes
tax-free debt a major competitive advantage for government-owned water
utilities.
-
THE WATER INDUSTRY FACES ENORMOUS CAPITAL INVESTMENT REQUIREMENTS Much of the capital infrastructure of the
water industry is at or beyond its useful service life. An
infrastructure-funding gap of $11 billion per year is projected for the next
twenty years. If such costs are passed through to consumers, 22% of American
households would pay more than 4% of their income for water – a hardship level
according to EPA benchmarks.
-
GOVERNMENT WATER UTILITIES WILL FIND IT INCREASINGLY ATTRACTIVE TO
PRIVATIZE. Looming capital investment requirements will present government
water utility managers with a set of unattractive choices: raise rates
substantially to pay for the new investment, allow water quality to
deteriorate, and/or engage in costly legal battles with the EPA. There will be an increasing temptation to
exit gracefully and hand the problem over to someone else. Serious regulatory issues must be resolved
(see below) before sales of public water works to private companies becomes
universally feasible.
- INVESTOR-OWNED WATER UTILITIES ARE ROUGHLY A THIRD MORE EFFICIENT THAN THEIR PUBLIC COUNTERPARTS. Whether measured by payroll per unit of water or rate of return on capital, investor-owned water utilities are, on average, more efficient than their public counterparts. The best practice government water utilities are only about as efficient as an average practice private utility. The best practice private utilities far outstrip the best practice government utilities.
-
DESPITE THEIR EFFICIENCY,
INVESTOR-OWNED WATER UTILITIES OFTEN CHARGE HIGHER RATES THAN PUBLIC
UTILITIES. This seeming anomaly reflects
the non-efficiency advantages of government owned utilities. Unlike private utilities they pay no taxes,
are subsidized by local tax revenues,
and have access to tax exempt debt (a subsidy from all federal
taxpayers). And unlike regulated private utilities, public utilities can amass
large amounts of cash for short-term investment income – in effect forcing past
ratepayers to subsidize current ratepayers.
-
WATER IS ‘UNDERPRICED’ IN THE
U.S. As a result of the subsidies noted above, water bills do not reflect the
true costs of producing water. This creates too much demand for water and
unnecessary damage to the environment. Government subsidies also facilitate
overstaffing, inefficient operations, and patronage in public utilities.
-
THE U.S. WATER INDUSTRY WILL ALWAYS POSSESS ATTRIBUTES OF ‘NATURAL
MONOPOLY”; SOME REGULATION WILL ALWAYS NECESSARY. Water is bulky, heavy, and
has a low per unit value. Transporting it for long distances is usually not
economically possible. This along with the lack of anything approximating the
national grids that exist in the electric, gas and telecom industries, make it
highly unlikely that the water industry, whether publicly or privately owned,
will ever be deregulated. Effective day-to-day competition for customers is
simply not feasible.
Our findings suggest that a restructuring of the
U.S. water industry, to take advantage of the benefits of market pressures, is
in the interest of the general public. Since investor-owned water companies are
more efficient than their government-owned counterparts, they can deliver
comparable services at a lower cost. This means that despite paying taxes to
local, state, and federal authorities, private water companies can supply water
for the same price as government-owned companies. The tax money, in turn,
instead of being lost to inefficient water services can be passed on to
consumers via tax cuts, or used to fund other government activities. The
equivalence between private and public water services despite the higher
operating costs of the former is possible because of the stronger incentives
for cost reduction in the privately owned companies. The profit motive provides
a reward structure for managers that operate in the best interest of the
general public.
Data presented below demonstrate that investor-owned
water companies operate more efficiently than publicly owned ones. It remains
unclear, however, whether this superiority extends to capital investment as
well. In theory, private companies determine infrastructure spending based on
need, subject to cost benefit analysis and the return on investment. In
practice private companies are subject to rate of return regulation which links
water rates to the amount invested – the rate base. If regulators set the
allowable rate of return too high, too much capital will be invested. If the
allowable ROI is set too low, too little capital will be forthcoming. Under
this regulatory regime operating efficiencies may raise ROI above the permitted
rate, forcing companies to cut water rates. Consumers alone will reap the
benefits of better operations. Neither the shareholders nor the managers of
private water companies benefit from enhanced efficiency.
Perhaps the best evidence of the failure of the
current regulatory framework is the inability of private U.S. water companies
to compete internationally. While U.S. computer and biotech companies dominate
their foreign competitors, French and British companies dominate the market for
new water and sewer systems. The absence of American water companies in the
global arena reflects the predominance of government ownership plus a private
water sector that is regulated on a rate of return basis and dominated by
cost-plus thinking. This regulatory environment is not conducive to the
creation of large efficient water companies capable of competing in
international markets.
Recommendations
1. ELIMINATE THE FEDERAL TAX
EXEMPTION FOR PUBLIC UTILITY DEBT. The exemption was intended as a subsidy for
state and local government borrowing. It may make sense to help such
governments defray the cost of police, fire, and other core services for which
private sector alternatives are not readily available. But private water companies, operating
without benefit of subsidies, have demonstrated their ability to provide water
services at prices comparable to those charged by government owned water
utilities. The exemption is a major obstacle to utility privatization.
Taxpayers and water users alike will benefit from elimination of the wasteful
subsidy for public utility debt.
Alternatively:
2. STATES SHOULD CREATE WATER
UTILITY “BANKS” TO ENABLE PRIVATE WATER
UTILITIES TO ACCESS THE TAX EXEMPT DEBT MARKET. The private utility would issue
it own (otherwise taxable) debt to the Water Utilities Bank, and as a
quasi-government entity the bank would in turn issue its own tax exempt
debt. The utility would receive the
proceeds for capital investment needs.
This concept is hardly novel.
States do it all the time with Industrial Revenue Bonds. Some states have set up higher education
funding authorities whereby private colleges and universities issue their own
(otherwise taxable) obligations to the authority which in turn issues it own
tax exempt debt of their behalf.
These changes will “level the playing field” between
private and government owned water utilities in the debt market.
3. REGULATORS SHOULD ALLOW
PRIVATE WATER UTILITIES TO USE PURCHASE PRICE ACCOUNTING RATHER THAN
DEPRECIATED BOOK VALUE OF ASSETS WHEN FIGURING THE RATE BASE OF AN ACQUIRED
UTILITY. Presently, a private water utility acquiring another faces serious
obstacles. Traditional rate of return
regulation recognizes only the depreciated book value of capital assets. Much of the acquired infrastructure is apt to
be very old and totally or largely depreciated.
The purchase price will greatly exceed (as a “going concern”) this
number. The acquiring utility will find
it difficult or impossible to recover their investment.
4. REGULATORS SHOULD CONSIDER ALLOWING UNFINISHED CONSTRUCTION TO BE INCLUDED IN A WATER UTILITY’S RATE BASE. Presently, there is some reluctance to undertake major capital project because of “rate shock” when a project is completed and comes on stream (and into the rate base) all at once. Phasing new construction in gradually as the project is underway smoothes out the rate increase.
Introduction
Water is unique.
Four things are necessary for the
most basic subsistence: air, water, food, and clothing and shelter in climates
where occasional cold can be life threatening.
Everything else is up the consumption chain.
Of the four, air is the most
important to our short-term survival.
Deprive the human brain of oxygen for five minutes, and we die. Air is not an economic good. It is a “free good”. We consume it from our first breath out of
the womb until our last gasp on earth.
But there are no meters on our chests with someone charging for every
breath.
Food is also necessary for
existence. But we can do without food
for periods of weeks or even months, if necessary, and still remain alive.
Water is in a unique position.
Humans can survive without it for a few days, at most. Water is the first item
up the chain of human survival from air.
It is more urgent than food, but less urgent than air. The occasional
protester may stage a “food strike”.
Have you ever heard of a “water strike”?
No commodity bought and sold in the economy is as
essential as water.
Early settlements clustered around a
source of fresh, drinkable water. There
was little choice except perishing from thirst.
It wasn’t until the Romans and their aqueducts that water could be
transported long distances. Many Roman
aqueducts are even today considered architectural and engineering marvels. They
were the first somewhat modern “water works”.
Fresh, pure water must be stored, treated,
transported to where it is needed and the wastewater disposed of. Doing these things is costly. Hence, water is not “free”, except perhaps to
a backpacker sipping from a glacier-fed stream.
Even then, the backpacker is likely to dump in a water purification
tablet…just in case. Unlike air, water
is an economic good carrying a price tag at the water meter.
Water covers two-thirds of the earth’s surface, but less than 10 percent of it is potable. Although the supply is finite, demand continues to grow exponentially. In areas where competition for water has been fierce, like the American West, a system of water rights has been set up to avoid the often bloody fights over ownership and use. In much of the world access to water is a matter of political power and its close relative, money. Yet waste and misuse are universal – clean water used to flush toilets or run factory equipment, for example – reflecting the misguided notion that water is limitless.
There is good news, however. As a nation, we have
recently cut back on water use. Since peaking in 1980, annual water withdrawals
are down by 472 gallons per capita, or 24%. The reduction mainly reflects new
water saving technologies in hydroelectric power and in agriculture, which
together account for about 80% of overall water usage. But private,
non-commercial usage is at or near all time highs. And overall usage is still
huge - about 1500 gallons of water per
day. Since 1940 overall total per
capita water usage is up by 46%; non-irrigation usage is up a whopping 98%.
(See chart below.)
Year
|
Total (Bil. Gallons) |
Per Capita (Gallons) |
Non-Irrigation Withdrawals
(Bil. Gallons) |
Per-Capita Non- Irrigation
Withdrawals
(Gallons) |
1940 |
140 |
1,027 |
69 |
506 |
1950 |
180 |
1,185 |
91 |
599 |
1955 |
240 |
1,454 |
130 |
788 |
1960 |
270 |
1,500 |
160 |
889 |
1965 |
310 |
1,602 |
190 |
982 |
1970 |
370 |
1,815 |
240 |
1177 |
1975 |
420 |
1,972 |
280 |
1315 |
1980 |
440 |
1,953 |
290 |
1287 |
1985 |
399 |
1,650 |
262 |
1083 |
1990 |
408 |
1,620 |
271 |
1076 |
1995 |
402 |
1,500 |
268 |
1000 |
Source: Statistical Abstract
of the United States, 1999.
We don’t see the big picture. Yes, we flush toilets,
take showers, make coffee and wash dishes.
Those things we understand. We
also eat fresh vegetables grown with irrigation water. We eat meat, eggs and milk. These require enormous amounts of fresh water
until the underlying plants and animals grow to maturity. We drive cars made from steel made in
water-hungry steel mills and consume other products made by a million other
industrial processes. These are water
uses we don’t see. But they are still real.
It’s still approximately 1500
gallons per day. Fifteen hundred gallons
is enough to fill the average backyard spa 4 times over. Fifteen hundred gallons is also enough to
fill an average backyard swimming pool in seventeen days. In other words, if you are a new pool owner
and don’t wish to consume any additional fresh water, you and your family must
go into a coma for 17 days to fill your pool with fresh water you otherwise
would have drank, flushed, or otherwise consumed.
Few of us would opt for that.
Instead, we argue in this study
that:
1. The U. S. water industry is currently reliable. We turn on the tap of a
faucet, and we expect the water to flow.
However, this is unlikely to be so in the future unless a serious
reorganization of the U. S. water supply takes place.
2. About 95% of the U. S. water
industry is in government hands. It is
operated and maintained either directly by a municipality or some sort of
regional government water authority.
3. Water is “underpriced” in
the United States. Thanks to subsidies – including the tax exempt bond interest
allowed government utilities – the water bills of government run systems do not
reflect the total cost of providing water to residents. As a result, Americans
consume more water than is economically justified.
4. Private companies have shown
they can provide clean water at a lower cost than publicly run systems.
Technical expertise, economies of scale, and customer service are on the side
of the private companies.
5. The trend around the world
is not to “socialize” the water industry.
It is sell public water assets to private companies or allow private
firms to operate government-owned water utilities.
6. The U. S. is far behind
other countries in this “demunicipalization” effort. Our economy and our environment will both
benefit from more private sector involvement in the provision of water.
Competition and
Privatization in the Water Industry
Market forces have been slow to come to the United States water industry. Many public water systems began as private, for-profit enterprises in the eighteenth and early 19th centuries. Over time devastating cholera epidemics and major fires in the nation's cities led Americans to view water as a public responsibility rather than a private commodity. As towns and cities expanded, most private water companies found they could not cope with the added costs while still maintaining reasonable rates for full-paying customers. By the turn of the century, more than 200 communities had shifted from private to public ownership. Municipally owned water works, acting as public monopolies, became the dominant national model for service delivery.
During most of the twentieth
century the public sector monopoly model was accepted uncritically.
Although the water industry
continues to be monopolistic in character, competitive forces began to be felt
in the 1990s. In the late 1980s, it was estimated that only 100 to 200 U.S.
water and wastewater facilities were under contracted operation. By 1997, a survey found this total to have
grown to more than 1,200 facilities in 44 states, including Puerto Rico, and
some industry watchers were predicting further growth in operations and
management contracting of 20 to 30 percent per year over the next five
years. Similarly, while there were still
only 17 publicly traded U.S. water companies as of 1998, many of these
investor-owned utilities are gaining territory through the acquisition of
smaller public and private systems. According to one survey of 10 such
utilities, total growth in net income increased by 13.5 percent in 1996 alone.
Private water utilities compete among themselves in a number of venues, including: extending service to unserved or underserved areas; engaging in acquisitions, mergers and hostile takeovers; bidding for operations contracts; purchasing water on wholesale markets; trading water rights; maintaining a service and quality image (e.g., bottled water); promoting private ownership and public-private partnerships.
The expanding number of competitors
in the water industry includes investor-owned water utilities, municipal water
utilities, nonutility contract operations firms, energy holding companies, and
foreign multinationals.
Some of the newer entrants to the competition have a
strong global presence and resources that far outweigh those of even the
largest U.S. water utilities. Powerful French water companies and newly
privatized British utilities are looking to buy American assets. In France,
private companies have long competed for long-term management contracts and
franchises, and have developed into multibillion dollar, highly sophisticated
international conglomerates. For example, Vivendi (formerly known as Compagnie
Générale des Eaux) took over the Houston‑based Professional Services
Group in 1980. Through this subsidiary Vivendi manages approximately 200
wastewater and 170 water facilities in the U.S., including contracts in Newark,
New Jersey, and Oklahoma City.
Similarly, Suez‑Lyonnaise des Eaux, another major international
company with origins in the French water industry, has partnered with United
Water Resources, one of the three largest investor‑owned U.S. water
companies, to operate more than 25 North American systems, including contracts
for a number of large utilities, such as Milwaukee, Indianapolis, Houston, and
Atlanta.
Along with the French,
several of the major privatized British water companies are also now active in
the United States and elsewhere around the globe. For example, Anglican Water
P.L.C. is partnering with the largest U.S. investor‑owned water company,
American Water Works, Inc., to compete for operations and management contracts
as American Anglican Environment Technologies, and is under contract from 1997
until at least 2002 to manage the Buffalo, New York water system, among others.
The private water industry is more profitable – on a
Return on Equity basis – than other regulated utilities. With sensible
regulation, a well-run water company can earn a return on equity of between 8
and 14 percent. On average, private
water companies use capital far more efficiently than do public water
utilities: only 6% of public utilities – the best in their class – perform
better than the average private utility, according to the Boston based BTI
Consulting Group.
In the restructured electric and gas industries,
direct competition among companies for the same customer base means lower
prices and lower profit margins. By diversifying into water, electric and gas
companies have the opportunity to raise their overall profitability. As a
result, mergers between water companies and newly competitive energy and
electric companies are likely. Combining metering, billing, customer service,
and back office operations would result in clear-cut efficiencies across
multiple utilities.
In what may prove to be the start of this trend,
Enron Corporation, one of the largest U.S. energy companies and a major player
in ongoing electric and natural gas deregulation, announced in July 1998 that
it was purchasing Wessex Water P.L.C., a British water and sewerage company.
Enron's chairman cited restrictions under the U.S. Public Utility Holding
Company Act as constraining such acquisitions in the U.S. With several bills in
Congress proposing to repeal this Act, however, the potential for future
realignment is rising.
Although water is a natural
monopoly, the influx of private companies looking for new acquisitions has
forced local water companies to act as if they had competitors. Private water
companies that overinvest in capital, pad payrolls, and otherwise let their
costs go out of control, will suffer declining stock prices. That will make
them vulnerable to hostile takeovers. The threat of new ownership is a powerful
incentive for management to think and act as if they faced direct competition.
Another form of competition – a better term, suggested by water analyst Janice Beecher, might be “contestability” – has sprung up between public and private water companies. Local governments, when faced with a prospective rate hike, will either seek out private managers or try to sell their publicly run water utility to a private company. (See the Atlanta section below.) On the other hand, a city served by a private water company can invoke its rights of eminent domain in an attempt to bring water under municipal control. In truth, good and bad performers are found on both sides of the privatization fence. A mixed system of private and publicly run water utilities is clearly optimal. The playing field, currently tilted against private ownership, must be leveled, however.
How Big is the U.S. Water Industry?
In
its most recent national survey (1997), the EPA found more than 180,000 public
water systems in the United States. This
total includes both “community” water systems serving at least 15 connections
or 25 residents year‑round, and “non-community” water systems, such as an
individual well serving a school or church, providing water to a nonresidential
population at least 60 days out of the year. Water that does not come from a
public water system, such as from a well serving one or just a few homes, is
considered a private supply and is excluded from the federal government's
statistics. While the nation's 50,289 community water systems in 1995
represented only 28 percent of all identified public water systems; they served
an estimated 93 percent of the U.S. population.
COMMUNITY WATER SYSTEMS IN THE U.S. 1995
Ownership
|
Number
|
% of Total Number
|
% of Total Population Served |
Annual Revenue ($ Billion) |
Public |
21,785 |
43% |
86% |
22.2 |
Private |
16,540 |
33% |
13% |
3.7 |
Ancillary |
11,960 |
24% |
1% |
NA |
Source: EPA, 1997.
Note: Community Water Systems serve at least 15
connections or 25 residents year-round, according to EPA and Safe Drinking
Water Act definitions.
Only 43 percent of the
nation’s community water systems are publicly owned, 33 percent are privately
owned utilities, and 24 percent were classified as "ancillary
systems" (i.e., very small systems, typically privately owned, that
provide water as an ancillary service to some other enterprise such as a mobile
home park). However, because most private systems are relatively small, an
estimated 86 percent of the U.S. population received its water from publicly
owned community systems, with only 13 percent relying on private utilities and
1 percent served by ancillary systems.
Total U.S. water industry
revenues were $25.9 billion in 1995, primarily from water sales, according to
this same EPA survey. Of this amount, 86 percent was received by publicly owned
systems, mirroring the percentage of the total population served by such
systems.
Factors Driving Water
Privatization
All
public services – not just water – are moving towards the use of market forces.
Privatization, deregulation, and competition have not only become public sector
buzzwords, but they have also become a reality in services ranging from
transportation to corrections, energy, and education.
The
dynamics pushing the water industry in this direction include:
1. Cost Control. The prospect of cost
savings and of cash up front are major drivers. In the water industry, private
operators are more efficient and less bureaucratic than government run
utilities. Large private water companies engage in R&D and hire the best
personnel. They are demonstrably ahead of government owned utilities in terms
of technology and state-of-the-art practices. Further, corporations are not
answerable to the electorate. Therefore they do not avoid the politically
distasteful, but often necessary, rate hikes needed to pay for vital
infrastructure. Unconstrained by public bidding and debt issuance requirements,
privately owned utilities often can finance construction projects at less cost
than government.
It would be wrong, however,
to assume that public water companies cannot change their practices. Many
government owned systems are evaluating their current operations against
industry best practice and are improving plant efficiency as a result. Some reportedly
have cut costs by nearly one-third and workforce by as much as 36% - to the
point where “Privatizers don’t even visit us anymore” according to Hagler
Bailly’s 1999 report to the National Research Council.
2. Federal Mandates. More stringent federal environmental
and public health regulatory standards, coupled with technological change, are
also contributing to increasing privatization. New drinking water regulations
phasing in at the start of the twenty‑first century as mandated under
1996 amendments to the SDWA, for example, are toughening standards for guarding
against bacteria and other microbial contaminants. In May 2000 EPA proposed new
rules to reduce arsenic in tap water which are expected to cost $375 million
per year. Earlier rules affecting chlorination and disinifectants will cost
over $1 billion per year nationwide (U.S. EPA, 1996 Clean Water Needs Survey
Report to Congress, 1998).
3. Infrastructure. America’s water systems
face an infrastructure-funding gap of $11 billion per year over the next 20
years, according to a report published by the Water Infrastructure Network in
April 2000. Water systems that currently
invest $13 billion a year to meet all capital needs would have to spend $24
billion. “This level of investment," the study notes “would be
unprecedented and would face considerable competition within local budgets from
operating and maintenance costs that are escalating by 6 percent a year above
the rate of inflation. Current federal contributions cannot help because they
have declined about 75 percent in real terms since 1980 and today represent
only about 10 percent of total capital outlays for water and wastewater
infrastructure and less than 5 percent of total water and wastewater outlays.”
An earlier estimate by the EPA’s Drinking Water Infrastructure Needs Survey
projected that $138.4 billion would be required for drinking water
infrastructure nationwide from 1995 through 2015, and many industry officials
believe the real cost will be significantly higher. Just for the replacement of
water mains and other aging distribution system infrastructure, for example,
the largest drinking water industry association, the American Water Works
Association (AWWA) estimates 20-year costs of $325 billion – more than four
times the EPA’s estimate of $77.2 billion.
4. Downsizing Government. The privatization movement
also has a purely philosophical aspect. Ideologues want less government, populists want a better society, both view privatization
as a means to that end. A central philosophical issue for government
policymakers is whether or not the provision of water services is a “core”
government function. Ideas about
government’s core functions are value-based and very personal. Most people agree courts and police are core
local government functions. Regulation
(including the economic, environmental, and social varieties) also is usually
considered core. But opinions differ
about road repairs, refuse collection, and schools. And of water service – is it “public works”
or a utility business? A related issue
is whether publicly owned water systems are accountable to taxpayers or ratepayers
(defined as water consumers.) The
utility’s perception of its clientele will shape its attitudes toward pricing
and privatization.
5. The Profit Motive. Even more important is the
profit motive among the various businesses engaged in privatization. Investor
owned utilities, contractors, their consultants, lawyers, and investment
bankers (who stand to make big fees helping private companies finance water
utility acquisitions), and members of the trade press have played a very active
part in promoting privatization, often to the exclusion of competing
perspectives. Privatization is good for
business, and is often the major source of revenue growth. So the commercial
interest in privatization should come as no surprise. But what is good for business is also good
for the public interest, at least with an appropriate system of
regulation. Regulators must weigh the
interests of consumers against the need for private firms to earn a competitive
profit rate.
While there are many valid reasons
for privatization, it may be worth calling attention to a few invalid
ones. These reasons may explain why
privatization often is viewed as a threat.
First, privatization should be not implemented out of fear,
intimidation, corruption, or a false sense of urgency (“now or never”). Second, cities should not avoid cashing in
for a one-time monetary windfall without
vision or purpose about the long-term interest of the community. Finally, privatization should be viewed as a
means to achieving other goals, not as an end unto itself. In other words, pure rhetoric or ideology is
not per se a valid reason for the privatization decision.
Thankfully, most privatizations are
motivated by a desire for efficiency and cost control. Pragmatism has been far
more important driver than ideology.
The Superiority of Privatization: A Statistical Analysis
Anecdotally, almost every
water privatization initiative claims to have cut costs. However, differences
in tax treatment and accounting methodologies, scale of operation, and local
operating conditions (e.g., source water, topography, and system age) make
apples to apples comparisons difficult. In one of the few such efforts, an
analysis of more than 100 water and wastewater utilities during the 1990s by
EMA Services, Inc., a major utility management consulting firm, identified an
average “competitiveness gap” of 24 percent greater costs for the public sector
in comparison to private sector industry leaders. (Paul Seidenstat et al., America’s Water
and Wastewater Industries: Competition and Privatization, Public Utilities
Reports, Inc., 1999.)
Along similar lines, a 1996 study sponsored by the
Reason Foundation concluded that California investor‑owned water
utilities provided “ comparable services to consumers at the same price as
government‑ owned water companies even though they pay taxes and do not
receive extra nonoperating income."
The Reason Foundation study
quantified the operating efficiency gap as follows:
Investor Publicly
Owned Owned
Total Operating Expenses per
Connection $272 $330
Employees per 1,000
Connections 1.62 1.49
Salaries as % of Operating
Revenues 13.40% 37.13%
Maintenance as % of
operating revenue
5.29% 9.13%
Staffing levels per
connection are more than twice as hogh at public water companies. As a result,
salaries consume more than one-third (37.1%) of operating revenues – or nearly
three times the share spent by private water companies. This is especially
troubling given the generally lower salaries paid by the government sector.
More evidence that public
water utilities are not run like businesses is found in 1 1999 report entitled
“Privatization of U.S. Water Utilities: Is There Anuthing More to Talk About?”
by Kenneth Rubin. CEO of Hagler Bailly Serbvices, Inc. Rubin cites the
following management comparisons:
Public Best
Average Practice
Average Annual Sick
Leave 9 days 3 days
Overtime 12% 4%
Time to procure $10,000
item 3 months 1 day
Core services are fom 25
percent to 35 percent more expensive in public utilities. According to the
Hagler Bailly analysis. This gap is attributed to inefficient work practices,
bureaucracy, and a lack of automation. By adopting more competitive strategies
public utilities couls cut chemical and energy costs by 15 percent. Supervisory
labor costs can be slashed by as much as 30 percent, operating labor costs by
15 percent, and maintenance labor by 18 percent.
The efficiency gap in
support services, a category that includes planning, engineering, construction,
human resources, accounting, and finance, is even greater. Between 24 percent
and 51 percent of the gap between inefficient public utilities and the best
private operators is caused by poorly provided support services, according to
the Hagler Bailly report.
Private ownership is not the
only path to efficiency. Government
owned water systems that contract out services to private operators are
demonstrably more efficient than those that do not. Using an industry-wide
database obtained from the American Water Works Association, we find that the
average cost per 1000 gallons of water is $3.41 for utilities that do everything
in-house, versus $2.62 per 1000 gallons for those that contract out more than
50% of their operations. The in-house only group needed 18.2 full employees per
each 1 billion gallons of water produced, versus only 14.2 employees per 1
billion gallons for the utilities that contracted-out.
A review of the recent
privatizations confirms the cost advantage of privately owned water systems.
Among recent STOP
Can We Afford Water? Equity
versus Efficiency
If local utilities had to finance
the entire infrastructure gap by themselves and pass the costs along to users,
water rates would more than double on average. Using the EPA’s benchmark that
families paying more than 2% of income for water bills constitutes a
“hardship,” even at today’s water rates some 18% of all U.S. households are
paying water fees that exceed hardship levels. By 2009, if the water and
wastewater funding gap was shouldered locally, at least 22 percent of U.S.
households would be classified as hardship cases under the EPA’s criteria.
The affordability issue is often cited as
justification for increased federal funding and continuation of the tax exempt
financing for government owned water works. There is another side to the story,
however.
Water is already heavily subsidized and is, therefore,
very under priced in the United States. A recent study by Raftelis
Environmental Consulting (Charlottesville, NC) shows that average U.S. utility
prices for drinking water range from a low of 0.007 cents/gallon to 0.042 cents/gallon, with an
average of 0.017 cents/gallon. While the
EPA states that water costs should be 2% of average household income, it
currently ranges between 0.5% to 1.0% - effectively a subsidy of well over
100%. [“U.S. Water Industry Crosses the
Threshold,” by Dan W. Noble, December 1999. Waterinvestments.com]
If there is one thing on which economists agree it
is on the elimination of subsidies that reduce economic efficiency and harm the
environment. Water subsidies are a textbook example. The current price of water
does not reflect the overall cost to society of producing this valuable
commodity. As a result: we consume too much water; we invest too much capital
to build water infrastructure; we utilize too much of our lakes and rivers as
reservoirs.
Efficiency demands that the price of water reflect
the cost of gathering, purifying, and distributing safe drinking water to
consumers. A price increase is justified on efficiency grounds. Higher water
bills will invariably reduce the demand for water. Full cost pricing would induce
changes in water use practices and promote innovative water saving
technologies, especially for high volume users. Higher prices, by insuring
efficient use of existing capacity, can help water systems defer, delay, or
downsize costly additions to supply-side capacity.
But what about equity? Water is a commodity so basic that no family
should have to devote more than 2% of its household income to it, according to
EPA guidelines. Many local politicians resist privatizing municipal water works
because such a move will often result in higher – unsubsidized – water bills.
But subsidizing water for all customers – rich and poor alike, - is hardly the
way to go. An income transfer program, modeled on the Low-Income Home Energy
Assistance Program, could help low income water customers cover the costs of
higher rates without distorting the market for water. Such income transfers are
much less damaging to the economy and the environment than subsidized water
rates.
Unfortunately, investor owned utilities face
powerful incentives to not curb water demand via higher prices. All utilities
depend on water revenues to cover costs. Private utilities must also earn a
return on capital. For privately owned utilities, the disincentive to raise
prices has been institutionalized through the state public utility commissions
responsible for regulating rates and returns. Public utility regulators
traditionally allow price hikes to maintain the rate of return on new
investment, but not to cover higher operating costs or to promote
conservation. A different regulatory
philosophy – recognizing the benefits of full cost pricing and conservation -
can correct the bias toward wasteful overinvestment in the water industry.
Privatization Models
As the U.S. water industry becomes more competitive, different
strategies for privatization and restructuring are being tried. The following
broad categories encompass the major approaches for injecting private sector
strengths and competition into this municipally dominated sector. We list them
in decreasing order of “privateness.”
Private
Ownership This is the purest form of privatization. Under
this model the ownership and operations of a municipal water system are sold to
a private company, converting a government enterprise into a regulated,
investor‑owned utility. Typically the purchasing company not only pays
the local government, but is also subject to additional terms and conditions –
e.g., limiting rate increases for some period, and/or establishing performance
goals – that go beyond standard regulatory requirements.
Contract
Operations and Maintenance (O&M) Under this approach, the
public sector retains ownership of its system, but contracts out operations to
a private firm. In full‑service contracting (also referred to as a "concession"),
all functions are operated by the private vendor. Most such contracts restrict
layoffs to attrition only. This is the most common form of public-private
partnership in the U.S. water industry,
Managed
Competition In
a managed competition, bids are solicited from potential contract operators and
compared to a proposal for restructured operation submitted by the public
sector's managers and employees. While non-economic factors may play a role in
such competitions, this award is typically made primarily on the basis of cost.
Outsourcing In this variation, non‑core
operations and maintenance activities are outsourced via competitive bids. As
with outsourcing in the private sector, this strategy is generally intended to
help an organization focus on its core business functions (e.g., treatment
plant operation, or pipeline maintenance) by using a specialized firm to manage
a function in which the utility is not as expert or proficient, and/or cannot
maximize efficiency and economies of scale (e.g., building and grounds
maintenance, billing and collections, meter reading, laboratory services).
Two Paradigms
Despite this apparent
variety there are really only two sharply contrasting models for privatization:
The “Ownership” model and the “Contract” model.
The ownership model is the “purest” form of
privatization. It consists of investor ownership, use of private capital for
major projects, and competition among private water companies. Almost all
investor-owned water utilities are subject to regulation by state public
utility commissions, which approve territories and terms of service,
investments, expenditures, prices, and rates of return (profits). Private water
companies generally charge higher rates than government run ones. This
differential does not reflect costs, which are usually lower in private hands.
Instead it reflects taxes (all levels), financing (including availability of
tax exempt financing for city owned utilities), subsidies (often hidden),
profits (return on equity), and the historic underpricing of water by many
cities.
Government run water companies have considerably
higher operating expenses than investor owned companies. They spend $330 per
connection as compared to $272 per connection, according to a 1996 study by the
Reason Foundation. Since there are no obvious differences in water quality or
dependability, the 18 percent difference reflects the loss in operating
efficiency under government ownership.
The major reason for the discrepancy: employment levels.
Investor owned firms hire 1.62 workers per every one thousand connections while
government owned firms employ over twice that amount at 3.48 employees per one
thousand connections, according to the Reason study. The actual differential is
probably higher, since public companies hire more contractors and consultants.
Political patronage jobs in government run utilities is undoubtedly part of the
explanation. Superior technology in private water works is another.
Large private companies, by consolidating many
plants and operations under one corporate umbrella, enjoy returns to scale
unavailable to government water utilities or local contractors. These efficiencies effect administrative
activities such as personnel, billing and collection, as well as the purchase
of treatment chemicals and executive management. Large companies also have
easier access to the capital markets and can often borrow at preferential
interest rates because of the large size of their capital funding. (This may
not fully offset the tax exempt interest rate advantage of public utilities
described below.) By buying neighboring utilities, private companies can
eliminate waste and excess capacity.
The economic advantages of size have spurred a
strong consolidation movement in the U.S. water industry. Private water
companies are scrambling to acquire government run utilities – and each other. In November 1998 California
Water Services (San Jose, CA) announced a bid for Dominguez Water (Long Beach,
CA). In March 1999, American States Water
(San Dimas, CA) made an unsolicited bid for Dominguez Water that was countered
and won by California Water Services. U.S. companies are even searching outside
of the country, with Azunix (a spin-off of Enron Corp) purchasing Wessex Water
in 1998.
The entry of Enron Corp., the largest natural gas
company in the United States, into the water industry is symbolic of a larger
trend: convergence of the water, electric, and natural gas industries. In any
geographic location, electric, gas, and water utilities are likely serving the
same customers. By diversifying into the water industry, electric and gas
utilities can expand their rate base and reduce unit costs.
Regulation
Privately owned utilities are regulated because they
have monopoly power over captive customers. We can find no major water
operation anywhere in the world which has been “privatized” without some type
of government control or regulation.
Water is simply “too important”
to be left to unfettered market forces..
There are three general types of government
regulation of the water industry: rate of return regulation, purchase price
regulation, and rate cap regulation.
These are generally identified with the United State, France and Great
Britain, respectively. There is
overlap. Not every single type of
government regulation is necessarily identified with one particular
country. And, water utilities who wish
to be privatized in other parts of the world have this smorgasbord from which
to pick. But, these are the general
models from which to pick.
We discuss rate of return regulation in the
following section. The French and British regulatory models are discussed on
pages TK through TK.
Rate of Return Regulation (RRR) is the most familiar to regulatory agencies
in the U. S., not just for water but also for most utilities. The concept is
simple. If a utility is a “natural
monopoly”, then it’s “rate of return” must be limited directly by regulators to
avoid “price gouging”. In the simplest
mathematical terms:
P=C x (1+r)
Where, P is the price of a unit of
water, C is the cost of producing that unit of water, and r is the allowable
rate of return (e.g. 6%, expressed in this case as 0.06).
This simple equation illustrates the tensions in this type of
regulation.
It is easy to see how perverse and
possibly conflicting incentives can arise under rate of return regulation. Utilities have an incentive to maximize total
net return (C x r). They are, after all,
private for profit entities. If they are not “efficient” (i. e. if “C” is
higher than necessary), the utility may actually benefit. So long as the utility’s rate of return, “r”,
exceeds the utility’s cost of capital, then some incentive exists to not necessarily
be as efficient as possible.
Regulators face a different set of incentives. In determining allowable
charges, regulators proceed on the premise that the return to capital invested
in private water utilities (ROI) should be in line with that earned in other
industries. If ROIs are too high/low, there will be too much/little capital
investment. Although the rule seems clear cut, it requires sound judgement as
to which costs are necessary and “allowable.”
It
is foolish to think that regulators are immune to political pressure when setting
rates – those in states in which commissioners are elected being the most
susceptible, those (primarily the large states such as New York and California)
in which they are appointed for long terms being the least prone to respond to
the political pressures of the moment. Whether elected or appointed, they want
happy customers (also known as voters).
One way to achieve this goal is to keep the price of water, “P”, as low
as possible and not rapidly rising. This
can lead to the regulators micromanaging a utility’s operations and
dissallowing vital capital outlays. (A large addition of capital plant, however
needed and justified, coming into the rate base “all at once” is apt to produce
politically unpalatable “rate shock” among ratepayers).
Rate of return regulation works best when there are no personal or
institutional ties between the regulators and the regulated utilities. This is
not always the case, however. A condition known as “capture” occurs when
management knows that regulators will permit any costs to be covered by higher
rates. When capture occurs, private utilities that over invest in capital, pad
payrolls, and otherwise inflate costs are rewarded with higher water rates. (In
the equation above, higher C leads to higher P.) Such utilities can actually
increase profits by raising costs.
The inefficiencies of such regulation may be exaggerated, however.
Because of the time regulatory commissions take to rule on rate cases,
utilities can often retain for their shareholders sums earned in excess of
allowable returns for several years. And because regulatory lag works in the
other direction – it takes a while for regulators to allow rate increases when
costs rise – utilities have a further incentive to keep costs under control. In
any event, these perverse incentives are checked by competitive forces
currently at work in the water industry, especially the proliferation of
private companies looking to acquire mismanaged – and therefore under-priced –
assets.
Traditional rate of return regulation can create
barriers to privatization. Most state regulatory commissions value utility
assets at book value rather than acquisition costs. As a result the rate base
is too small to allow an acquiring utility to earn a reasonable return on its
new investment. Water systems in such states will not be attractive to
potential buyers. But for the regulator to allow the purchase price, or market
value, to become the rate base on which the allowed return is to be computed,
would be to engage in a circular process, since the market value is itself a
function of the rates the regulator will allow. To use reproduction costs as
the rate base is to launch on a process involving “endless controversy over the
proper valuation of sunk capital, in direct contradiction of the economic
principle that sunk investment costs are prominent among the 'bygones' that
ought to be ignored in price making.” (Alfred E. Kahn, The Economics of
Regulation: Principals and Institutions, New York, John Wiley &
Sons, 1970, Vol. I, pp. 53-54.)
Profit sharing agreements, under which the
efficiency benefits arising from privatization are shared between the acquiring
utility and its customers, can be a pro-privatization alternative to
traditional rate of return regulation.
In the end, privatization will involve a multiparty bargain between the private
sector buyer, the municipality or other public sector seller, the regulator,
and, perhaps, the EPA, the latter having a major say in the magnitude and
timing of future capital investment. The difficulty of achieving such a
bargain, along with the tax preference accorded public sector debt, explain the
popularity of long-term contracting as opposed to the outright sale of public
water utilities to private water companies.
Tax and Political Barriers to
Private Ownership
Despite the obvious advantages of private
ownership, sales of government owned water utilities to private companies have
been fairly rare in the 1990s. Such sales typically involve the sale of smaller
water systems to existing, neighboring investor‑owned water utilities
that offer economies of scale and more sophisticated management. For example,
in 1996 alone, United Water Resources acquired two small New Jersey systems to
gain approximately 40,000 new customers, Consumers Water Company purchased
three local systems, and the Philadelphia Suburban Corporation acquired eight
systems to add over 17,000 new customers (Price Waterhouse, 1997). In the
wastewater industry, the first sale of a federally subsidized municipal
wastewater facility ‑ the Franklin Area Wastewater Plant in southwestern
Ohio ‑ took place in 1995, and has not been widely replicated.
The major obstacle to the
sale of municipal water assets in the second half of the twentieth century is
the structure of the U.S. tax code. Municipal debt continues to be tax‑exempt,
while privately issued debt remains taxable. As a consequence, public utilities
enjoy lower capital costs than privately owned utilities. This is seen in the
interest rate differential between tax exempt municipal bonds and corporate
debt:
The
Spread Between Taxable and Tax-Exempt Interest Rates
Year |
Municipal
Bond Interest
Rate (High
Grade) |
Corporate
Bond Interest
rate (Baa) |
Spread:
Municipal Less Corporate Bond Interest Rate |
1980 |
8.51% |
13.67% |
5.16% |
1985 |
9.18 |
12.72 |
3.54 |
1990 |
7.25 |
10.36 |
3.11 |
1991 |
6.89 |
9.80 |
2.91 |
1992 |
6.41 |
8.98 |
2.57 |
1993 |
5.63 |
7.93 |
2.30 |
1994 |
6.19 |
8.62 |
2.43 |
1995 |
5.95 |
8.20 |
2.25 |
1996 |
5.75 |
8.05 |
2.30 |
1997 |
5.55 |
7.86 |
2.31 |
1998 |
5.12 |
7.22 |
2.10 |
1999 |
5.43 |
7.87 |
2.44 |
Source: Economic Report
of the President, February 2000.
The spread results in
significantly lower debt service costs. For example, cumulative interest
payments on a $1 million thirty-year bond would be $497,000, or 53% more at the
current corporate interest rate (7.87%) than they would at the municipal bond
rate (5.43%). This is particularly important given the highly capital‑intensive
nature of the water industry.
Federal subsidies also favor
public ownership. For years following the passage of the Clean Air and Water Act,
federal construction grants were made available to public utilities only. This made it difficult for any private
utility to play a leadership role in addressing the environmental goals of that
era. It also made subsequent ownership changes impractical. Until 1992,
municipalities were required to repay all such federal grants they had received
upon sale to a private operator. In 1992, however, President George Bush's
Executive Order (EO) 12,803 on Infrastructure Privatization gave municipalities
new flexibility to sell public infrastructure while only being required to
repay any remaining "undepreciated" portion of the grant. Also, in
response to EO 12,803, the EPA announced its intent to allow private operators
to receive federal assistance. In conjunction with the decreasing availability
and significance of such subsidies in the 1990s, this policy change has served
to shift the playing field much closer to a level position.
Political concerns over water rates
and the control of water systems may limit the sale of government water
utilities to private firms. For local politicians, control is often the central
issue in the water industry. He who controls water, controls the economic
destiny of the city or town. In this respect, the water industry is more local
in character than other utilities (electricity and gas). Even when a privatized
water utility might lower water costs through economies of scale or increased
operating efficiencies, local communities are often reluctant to surrender
control over rates and finances to state regulatory bodies. Considerable
evidence suggests that many long-term contracts are structured to avoid
economic regulation by the states, to the liking of both the privatizers and
the cities in which they operate.
For
small communities near major investor-owned utilities, however, the economies
of scale afforded by such larger systems may overwhelm such drawbacks. These communities may also be motivated by the one‑time influx
of capital that such a major asset
sale may bring. For example, after paying off its system debt, Franklin, Ohio's
$6.8 million sale generated more than $1 million in proceeds for the county and
municipal governments served by the plant. Similarly, in 1998, the Mayor of
Birmingham, Alabama proposed the sale of that city's water and sewer system
primarily to capitalize a school construction trust fund, following voter
disapproval of a sales tax increase targeted for school improvements. Perhaps
exemplifying the difficulty of such a major sale, however, Birmingham voters
rejected this proposal in a November 1998 referendum.
Some regions of the country, such as Pennsylvania
and New Jersey, have begun to see significant use of this strategy. Most areas
of the nation do not yet have private water utilities large enough to pursue
this approach. Absent dramatic government intervention to overhaul the tax
code, modify environmental regulations, and generally restructure the market,
asset sales face far greater obstacles than less pure forms of privatization.
Long term contracting is by
far the most widespread form of privatization. It has changed the economics and
politics of the water industry in many fundamental ways. Perhaps reflecting the influx of French
investors and parent companies into the U.S. water market, this model closely
parallels the competitive system of France. Its popularity, however, is clearly
the result of recent changes in the U.S. tax code.
Following substantial
lobbying from the United States Conference of Mayors, the Department of the
Treasury issued new tax regulations in 1997 enabling long-term private
contracting for water operations and management. Under previous rules, if a
publicly owned water facility was under contract operation for more than five
years, it was deemed to be for “Private Use” and ineligible for tax-exempt
capital financing. Under the 1997 modifications, however, contracts of up to 20
years are now permissible without affecting the tax-exempt status of a
utility's debt. With longer term contracting now practicable, long-term capital
investments can be incorporated into O&M agreements and amortized over a
period that makes such agreements more cost-competitive.
Contract provisions vary
significantly. For example, Buffalo adopted a five-year contract (with a
five-year renewal option) in 1997 with American Anglican Environment
Technologies for full-system operation. Buffalo's contract, which is projected
to save $23 million, or 30% of pre-contract operating costs, over the first
five years, guarantees no layoffs and continued civil service status for the
municipal employees of the system. Indianapolis selected a contract team made
up of a private treatment plant operator and its local public employee union,
saving over 25 percent ($13 million over five years) on managing its wastewater
system. Late in 1998, Atlanta gained widespread attention by reaching a 20‑year
agreement to manage its water system; the largest yet operated under contract.
(See below.) As evidence of intense
private sector interest in such opportunities, Atlanta required interested
parties to pay a nonrefundable $50,000 fee just to participate in the
bidding. Five companies bid for the
project.
The length of the contract
is crucial. Short term O&M contracts usually do not offer large enough
total dollar savings to cover capital investment needs. The kind of operating and capital changes
required to generate 20 percent and greater operating cost savings take time to
implement. Long-term contracts allow
municipalities and private contractors to share and spread risks appropriately
and efficiently, and implement a broader range of cost saving measures.
More than any other device, long-term contracts have
brought large domestic and foreign companies into the water market. Such arrangements, by obviating the need for
costly re-bids every few years, are much more attractive to the industry.
Although experience with long-term contracting is limited, casual observation
suggests that average annual cost savings from long-term contracts are greater
than average savings from successive short-term ones. This seems to validate the industry’s
contention that more efficiency can be realized over a longer period.
Long-term contracts have also reduced opposition to
privatization by public employee unions.
It is increasingly common for long-term O&M contracts to require
that all employees be hired by the winning bidder (save those who cannot pass a
drug test), and that contractors not lay off any of those employees for a set
period (usually at least one year). Large water companies tend to operate with
about one-third fewer workers than government does. The natural turnover rate
of employees can bring the total number of employees down to the desired level
(i.e. where the private firm can make a profit at the contract price they bid)
in around 3-5 years. So, for short-term
contracts, no-layoff provisions would mean no profits, and so were rarely
seen. With long-term contracts they are
becoming the norm.
Another labor issue is that of employee benefits. Recent
years have seen many private firms offer wages that are converging on those
employees earned from local government, but benefit packages lagged. Notably, private sector defined contribution
pension plans were viewed as inferior to public-sector defined benefit pension
plans. With the splendid performance of
the stock market in recent times, defined contribution plans have begun to look
more attractive. Also, private pension
plans often have much shorter vesting periods, and many governments are
converting to defined contribution pensions. These developments have to some
extent closed the gap between private and government benefits packages.
Public officials are reluctant to relinquish control over
water rates and availability. In many parts of the west, control over water is
tantamount to control over economic growth and activity. Long-term contracts
may exacerbate that concern. On the other hand, there is a growing realization
that the higher user fees necessitated by capital improvements have very
regressive effects on local residents.
This realization is changing the politics of privatization. As Atlanta’s liberal mayor showed,
conservatives do not own privatization policy.
His core constituency, the urban poor, stood to loose the most from the
expected 100 percent increase in rates if the public works department continued
to operate the water system.
Long-term privatization also challenges the rationale for
a growing policy practice—managed competitions.
In managed competitions in-house employees bid against private firms for
the contract. Since a significant advantage of long-term privatization comes
from shifting risks to the private sector, it is very difficult for an in-house
team to offer competitive bids. To date,
no long-term contracts have been bid as managed competitions. This may turn out to be a non-problem, since
much of the reason for managed competitions is to assuage public employee
unions objections to privatization, and long-term contracts offer full-hire
provisions in its place.
Disadvantages start with the inevitable conflict of
interest that exists whenever principals (governments) delegate
responsibilities to agents (contractors). Which party is responsible for
environmental compliance or the planning or implementation of needed
infrastructure investments? Will the government blame the contractor? Will the
contractor blame the government? This ambiguity is, of course, absent when
water works are privately owned.
Contracts are growing longer in length and more lucrative financially, to the obvious benefit of the contracting community. Larger and longer contracts reduce risks and enhance profitability, but they also have negative implications. First, they narrow the field of viable competitors, resulting in an oligopolistic market. Second, they challenge the capacity of local governments to design and oversee contracts to protect their interests over the long haul. Experienced contractors generally have the advantage in the contracting process. Third, and perhaps most important, they suggest the possibility of monopoly power and potential for abuse over time.
Contracting is oligopolistic at the bidding stage
because few firms qualify, but is monopolistic once the contract is awarded,
with relatively weak competitive pressure over time. The problem of persistent
monopoly power is perhaps the most important consideration for policymakers. As
analyst Janice Beecher writes: “A twenty-five year cycle of bidding – however
intense the bidding – hardly constitutes robust competition. The competition is intermittent at best. Moreover, the contracts model is designed
rather transparently to circumvent the authority of the state to regulate
monopolies and their profits. In other
words, contracts effectively eliminate regulatory risk to the private
firm.” [Janice A. Beecher,
“Privatization, Monopoly, and Structured Competition in the Water Industry: Is
There a Role For Regulation?”, 1999.]
Governments must be “smart buyers" when deciding
how to share power with private contractors. Bidding often presumes maintenance
of current prices with no assurance that savings or “profits” will be used for
system improvements or to lower water bills.
Good contracting requires crystal-clear performance incentives and
meaningful enforcement mechanisms. There is no fool-proof mechanism for
achieving this; “best practices” are not well established. In practice,
contracting is rife with favoritism, waste, fraud, and corruption involving
public and private partners. In Sharing
Power author Donald F. Kettl writes that “Despite the enthusiasm for
entrepreneurial government and privatization, the most egregious tales of
waste, fraud, and abuse in government programs have often involved greedy,
corrupt, and often criminal activity by the government’s private partners – and
weak government management to detect and correct these problems.”
The regionalization of small local water companies
is impossible if they are managed under private contact. Spatial and temporal
boundaries will prevent optimal long-term solutions. A patchwork of private
contracts, in other words, will not help the water industry achieve much needed
economies of scale through the formation of publicly or privately owned
regional systems.
Another negative is the tendency for governments to focus
on short-term contractual benefits while ignoring long-term disadvantages. Some long-term contracts include large
concession fees, paid by the contractor to the local government, that represent
some portion of future cost savings.
(Another way to describe them is as the present-discounted value of
future user fee increases.). However stated, the practice means that future
rate-payers will pay higher rates than they might otherwise would have as a result
of current Mayor’s desire for a pot of unencumbered dollars to spend as he
wishes. Even if that money is used in an
actuarially wise fashion, such as on infrastructure, there may be considerable
resource misallocation.
Contracting proponents maintain that private contractors will provide the best service at the lowest price in order to renew their government contracts as they expire. In many cases, however, the problems are due to insufficient or out of date infrastructure rather than inefficient operations. Contractors manage the operations side, not the capital and infrastructure side of water utilities. If a municipality feels there is no way, even with the help of an private O&M contractor, that it can raise the funds needed to revitalize its infrastructure, then the outright sale of water assets to a private company is clearly the best alternative.
Given the economic and political advantages of private
ownership, there is little doubt that many local governments choosing long-term
O&M contracts would have chosen to sell the water utility outright were it
not for our perverse tax code. The interest rate advantage for public ownership
makes contracting the more attractive option even if operational and
administrative efficiencies favor a sale or lease. Therefore a good argument
can be made for leveling the playing field by either eliminating the tax
exemption for public borrowing, or making it available to all utilities –
public and private alike.
Other Regulatory Models:
France has a long history of private water utilities. In 1782 a private company was given a
franchise to distribute water to Paris.
From the early 1850’s, other cities (Cannes, Le Havre, Calais) were
giving their water franchises to private firms.
Private water companies including such international giants as Vivendi
currently serve nearly 75% of the French water market,.
French water utility regulation relies principally
on market forces. A franchise to provide
water in a given area is put up for bids.
The franchise is good for a specified number of years. Government involvement is limited to drafting
a bid document and monitoring compliance by the successful bidder over the life
of the franchise. Typically the
franchise agreement will specify prices which may be charged (which may
increase by specified amounts over the life of the franchise depending on the
terms of the successful bid) and certain measures of quality of product and
service.
These bid documents are fairly easy to draft. The technology of the water utility business
is widely known and changes relatively slowly.
Measures of water quality and levels of service are also widely known.
Barrriers to entry are thus limited, ensuring a healthy number of bids.
France uses two main types of regulation. One is the concession under which private
water utilities are invited to bid on a long-term franchise to build and/or
modernize the capital plant. The utility
agrees to provide the funds for the capital outlay and to operate the
facility. Concession arrangements are
popular where the municipality either lacks the funds for, or doesn’t wish to
assume the risk of financing the capital
facility itself.
The second
is the affermage system. In the affermage
system, there is still a bidding process on price and quality for operation
of the facility, but the municipality itself advances the funds to underwrite
the capital outlay. The governmental
unit still owns the facility. In many
cases, the bid document will specify a bond to be forfeited if the facility is
not turned over to its governmental owner in a specified condition at the end
of the contract. This is not unlike
putting down a security deposit when leasing an apartment.
Both forms of regulation have “self-enforcing”
safeguards. First, private bidders have an incentive to bid as low as they
reasonably can on the present and future price(s) of water they agree to
provide. Otherwise a competitor may
steal the contract. Second, the
successful bidder retains an incentive to wring efficiencies from the
operation. After all, the price(s) of
water at a given point in time are fixed by the agreement. Ratepayers are protected from and undue
“cutting of corners” by the quality of service and product provisions of the
agreement.
Franchise bidding obviously tends to work better
with larger water systems. If the
operation is small, it may be “not worth the effort” to attract more than one
or a handful of bidders. In this case,
the competitive bidding market to provide a specified level of quality at the
lowest price tends to break down due to lack of competition.
Nonetheless, franchise bidding has often worked well
in France and elsewhere when the circumstances are right.
Great Britain was rather late in coming to the idea
of privatizing water utilities.
A variety of new regulatory regimes are available to
regulators who fear that traditional rate-base, rate-of-return regulation
offers too little incentive to efficiency. These include the regulation of
prices rather than profits, so that cost savings are shared between customers
and shareholders, and the use of intercompany cost comparisons, or
benchmarking. A radical new approach, much used in the U.K., regulates firms by
use of a price cap. One formula is that regulated prices should rise at
“inflation minus X.” Under this approach water prices go up at the annual
inflation rate less an annual efficiency improvement (“X”). The advantage of
this approach is that it mimics a competitive market. Firms do not control
prices – they become “price takers” – and any cost reduction flows directly
into profits. Difficulties arise over the appropriate value for X. If X is set too high, the water system will suffer
chronic losses; if X is too small, companies will earn large monopoly profits.
Can Water Be Deregulated?
A natural monopoly exists when only one producer can
operate profitably in a given market.
This alone is not enough. There
must also be substantial barriers to entry for potential competitors so that the natural monopoly company has
little or no fear of future competitors.
Is water a natural monopoly? Free market advocates say
no, pointing to deregulation occurring in other U.S. utilities, particularly
electric and gas utilities in the late 1990s.
Among energy utilities, previously integrated services of production,
distribution, and marketing have been "unbundled" to create new areas
for competition. While distribution must generally remain a regulated monopoly,
new deregulation policy is enabling electric companies to compete as either
producers and/or retail marketers. Electric power can be transmitted over long
distances at a cheap price (called “wheeling of power”). Electric utilities are
being given much more ability to merge and engage in power wheeling by state
regulatory commissions.
But neither the technology nor the economics of
water permit such competition. Drinking water quality can degrade over time and
distance, and water from different sources
may not react well upon mixing. Water is bulky. Transporting it for long
distances via pumping stations and expensive pipeline infrastructures costs a
great deal of money relative to the price of the water being moved.
Water requires much more infrastructure to produce and
distribute than other basic services. Water utilities require as much as $12 in
capital investment for every $1 in revenue.
Comparable numbers for electric utilities are roughly $4 for every
revenue dollar generated, $3 for basic telephone companies, and $2 for
railroads. This has two implications:
(a) capital requirements make competitive entry difficult and contribute to the
“natural monopoly" nature of the water business, and; (b) cost of capital is crucial in
determining the profitability and viability of a water utility, whether public
or private.
Unlike electricity or natural gas, water is a
“local” commodity. There will always be a monopoly element, requiring economic
regulation by either local governments or state public service commissions.
A possible exception can be found in the water
starved Southwestern U.S. Infrastructure is in place connecting the Colorado
River to Phoenix and Tucson via the Central Arizona Project, and to Los Angeles
and San Diego via the Colorado River Aqueduct. The State Water Project in
California transports water from the Bay Area to Southern California. This
massive infrastructure coupled with rapid growth and a severe water shortage
may support the development of a water market comparable to those seen in electricity
and natural gas.
The "unbundled"
energy utility model may have other applicability. In some metropolitan areas
both conservation successes and demographic shifts from city to suburb have
left larger systems with excess capacity that can provide more cost‑effective
"production" than building or upgrading nearby smaller plants. Under
a different regulatory structure, such economies of scale might be better
captured through selling water to a neighboring utility.
Atlanta provides water and
wastewater service to more than 1.5 million people. The city owns and operates two water
treatment plants, with a capacity of 201.4-mgd; three major pumping stations;
90.5 million gallons of storage; and 2,400 miles of water mains. In addition
there are three wastewater treatment plants and a 2,200 mile sewer system.
Like many metropolitan areas of the
United States, Atlanta’s water and sewer systems are deteriorating and in need
of massive capital improvements. The city’s 1997 Capital Improvement Plan
called for spending $850 million over the next five years to replace and
upgrade antiquated facilities, provide for future capacity, and meet
environmental requirements. Faced with
the need to finance immediate capital improvements, Atlanta was faced with two
choices: raise water rates again to meet operations and debt service
requirements, or cut operating expenses to offset higher debt service costs.
The city decided in June 1997 to
assess ways of cutting costs. In July 1997 the city retained a group of
consultants to evaluate possible alternatives for cost savings and technical
improvements. The consultants outlined several different methods for obtaining
cost savings: internal re-engineering, outsourcing, managed competition under
which public employees could compete with private contractors, contract
operations of facilities, and private system management. The consultant team
estimated the savings that could be derived from each of the options, and
assembled them into savings packages or alternatives. The range of annual
savings predicted by the consultant’s model went from $14.9 million per year
for light re-engineering/outsourcing to $39.6 million for the most dramatic
alternative: placing the entire water and wastewater systems under private
management.
In December 1997 Bill Campbell, the
populist Democrat mayor of Atlanta, decided on private management of the city’s
water utility and the largest wastewater treatment plant. “I am not a fan of privatization,”
the Mayor wrote. "But my personal philosophy is that we serve the public’s
best interest by not closing our eyes to the reality that if we fail to
privatize, we will be forced to severely raise rates.” The mayor’s political
calculus was actually quite simple. The city water system was significantly out
of compliance with environmental standards, leading the federal government to
fine the city on a daily basis. The
water utility’s own estimate of the cost to upgrade the system and achieve compliance
called for a more than 100 percent increase in water rates, which caused an
uproar among residents, especially the poorer neighborhoods which are the
mayor’s power base.
Atlanta set an ambitious schedule
for the procurement process, looking to close on a contract less than one year
from the issuance of its RFP. One reason for the tight scheduling was that the
savings anticipated through privatizing the water system had to be “bankable”
when the city sold its next issue of tax exempt water bonds. Otherwise the
rating agencies would have downgrade the securities and interest costs would
have risen. Because the main goal of this privatization was to offset rate
increases and pay for new capital spending, the city needed to have a
contractor identified with a guaranteed level of savings when it went into the
bond market in late 1998 or early 1999.
Many problems were noted in the
city’s plan. Among them: the hurried schedule for the bidding process; a lack
of specific details regarding oversight for both bidding procedures and
operation of the system; and ambiguity surrounding plans for about half the
capital improvements. National experts on privatization expressed concern with
the speed of the process of selecting a contractor. The proposals were due from
bidders on July 2; the City picked a vendor on August 12th. Conflict
of interest questions dogged the selection of an Atlanta law firm with ties to
Mayor Campbell to represent the city in the privatization process.
After an extremely hard-fought
competition among private firms, the city chose a joint venture of United Water
Services and its parent Lyonnaise des Eaux to operate and maintain the system
for 20 years (The other competitors for the contract were Vivendi’s Compagnie
Général des Eaux, U.S. Filter Corp., and a joint venture of the U.S. firm OMI
and Thames Water). The agreement cuts the cost of upgrading and operating the
utility by 44 percent, and means water rates need increase less than 30 percent
to pay for the upgrades. The city’s annual cost was $49.5 million, and United
Water’s bid only $21.4 million a year.
However, the city will also pay roughly $6.1 million a year to cover the
costs of electricity, natural gas, and insurance for the facilities, as well as
contract monitoring costs.
United Water hired all 535 existing
water department employees. The firm will operate the city’s two water
treatment plants, and all meter reading, billing, and customer service
responsibilities. Atlanta still owns the system, and will continue to set
rates, finance capital improvements, assume all market risk for delivery of raw
water to the treatment plants, and ensure contract compliance.
United Water agreed to a no-layoff
(without cause) policy for the 535 employees of the city water department for
the full duration of the contract, which exceeds the city’s request for a
three-year period. The firm will use
early retirement incentives, drug and alcohol screening, cross-training and
transfers of skilled operators and managers within its regional operations,
planning to reach optimum employment levels in two years.
The politics of the contract process
were not pretty. The RFP was modified 18
times after it was issued, and a final 80-page version was issued only two days
before final prices were due. Nonetheless, an independent reviewer hired to
watchdog the process judged the process to be fair, if not the best he’d ever
seen.
Observers, and bidders, were
surprised when the city decided to provide first-round prices to local
newspapers and technical bid summaries to each of the bidders. They then asked
the bidders to improve all aspects of their proposals for best-and-final offers
three weeks later. But the city may have been crazy like a fox—United Water’s
winning bid was 21 percent lower than its original!
And the firm not only cut the price,
it also upped its efforts in other measures. The city set a quota of 30 percent
minority participation—United Water came back with a plan have 35 percent
ownership of its local operating company owned by local minority businesses,
and 60 percent of the system management be minorities. Not only that, but the
firm agreed to move some corporate offices and invest 5 percent of its pretax
profit in job training and economic development in the city’s economically
distressed neighborhoods. This gave the
Mayor great leverage in selling the privatization to his constituents, and took
the contract to new heights in contract terms unrelated to the service being
contracted.
The single most defining event in
water privatization over the past decade has been the advent of long-term
contracts. Atlanta’s 20-year agreement to manage its water system is the
largest such contract signed in the United States. What lessons about future
privatizations does the Atlanta contract teach us? Here are the broad trends
implied by the contact:
1. Privatization of
infrastructure is now on the table in the nation’s big cities. Other big cities
like Seattle, Chicago, and Houston have dabbled in partial privatization
already. The environmental and fiscal pressures on them are beginning to
outweigh the traditional political powers of public-employee unions and the
belief that privatization is too risky.
2. Many contracts will entail
hiring all existing employees. This trend has been emerging ever stronger in
the last few years. Employees like it, for obvious reasons, and if they fail to
stop a privatization from occurring in the first place, this is often their
first demand. Interestingly, most of the private firms do not oppose the
idea. They see it as helping reduce
ill-will associated with privatization, and in fact have always on average
hired over half of existing employees for their intimate knowledge of the local
system.
3. Most contracts will be
long-term. It takes 10 years or more of significant operating efficiencies to
pay for the upgrades most systems need, especially if the private firm is
putting up some of the capital. Moreover, political pressure makes firing
existing employees difficult. Thus while a private firm typically uses
two-thirds the personnel to operate a given system, it usually takes years
after privatization for natural employee turnover to bring manning levels down
that far. United Water Services has lost money on the Atlanta contract, and
will not earn a profit on it for several more years – when manning levels are
diminished.
4. Large cities are at an
advantage when it comes to privatization. Water companies crave the exposure
and publicity that comes from operating in a large metropolitan area. They will
sacrifice profit margins, and submit bids at or even below cost in order to
come in with the winning bid. Expect other large city contracts to be laden
with unrelated “community benefit” requirements. Minority participation requirements are old
hat, but the Atlanta contract in particular opened the door to all manner of
stratagems from corporate office locations to school programs. Such provisions
appeal to big city politicians but greatly reduce the economic advantages of
privatization.
5. A troubling development
arising from long-term contracts like Atlanta’s concerns inter-generation
equity. The contract included large
concession fees, paid by the contractor to the local government, that represent
some portion of the present-discounted value of future operating cost
savings. Another way to describe them is
as the present-discounted value of future user fee increases (or lack of
decrease made possible by future operating efficiencies). However stated the practice means that future
rate-payers will pay higher rates than they might otherwise have to as a result
of current policy-maker’s desire for a pot of unencumbered dollars to spend as
they will. Even if that money is used in
an actuarially wise fashion, such as on infrastructure, there may be
considerable dead-weight loss during the transfer.
6. The politics of
privatization will not always follow conventional thought. Atlanta’s liberal
mayor showed conservatives do not own privatization as a policy. As liberals
begin to realize that the cost of improving infrastructure, even with
tax-exempt funding, is much more of a burden on the poor than the middle-class
or wealthy, they will embrace the efficiency gains that accompany competition
7. Expect to see employees of
privatized utilities strive to keep their public-sector defined-benefit
pensions. There is a move in the public
sector to convert to defined contribution pension systems. To the extent that occurs, public pensions
will have no particular advantage over private ones, which are mostly defined
contribution.